class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide # 2.1 — Tariffs ## ECON 324 • International Trade • Fall 2020 ### Ryan Safner
Assistant Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/tradeF20
tradeF20.classes.ryansafner.com
--- class: inverse # Outline ### [Tariffs](#3) ### [Effects of an Import Tariff in a Small Country](#14) ### [Effects of an Import Tariff in a Large Country](#14) ### [Optimal Tariff Theory](#14) ### [The Effective Rate of Protection](#14) --- class: inverse, center, middle # Tariffs --- # Tariffs, According to the President of the United States .pull-left[ .center[ ![](../images/trumptariffs1.png) ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](../images/trumptariffs2.png) ] ] --- # Tariffs, According to Professional Economists .pull-left[ .center[ ![](../images/IGApollfreetrade.png) .source[Source: [IGA Experts Poll (2012)](http://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/free-trade)] ] ] -- .pull-right[ .center[ ![](../images/tariffsbad.jpg) ] ] --- # International Trade Policies .pull-left[ - Economists generally agree that free trade best enhances overall social welfare - Yet free trade is rare in the world - Two questions: 1. Why is free trade rare? Or, why are trade restrictions common? 2. What are the consequences of restricting trade? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](../images/tradeportship.jpg) ] ] --- # International Trade Policies .center[ ![:scale 50%](../images/usprotectionism2015.png) .smallest[ This was in 2015, before the Trump Administration! ] ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Tariffs --- # Tariffs .pull-left[ .smallest[ - Most common way to restrict trade is through a .hi[tariff] (historically called a .hi[“duty”]), a tax specifically targeted towards internationally-traded goods - .hi[Import tariff]: tax on imported goods - This is by far the most common type of trade restriction - .hi[Export tariff]: tax on exported goods - Rare in developed countries but sometimes occurs in developing countries as a way to generate government revenue ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ] --- # Types of Tariffs .pull-left[ .smallest[ - .hi-purple[Ad valorem tariff] taxes a fixed percentage of the value of a good - e.g. 25% U.S. tariff on (prices of) imported trucks - .hi-purple[Specific tariff] taxes a fixed sum per unit of a good - e.g. $3/barrel of oil - .hi-purple[Compound tariff] combines ad valorem and specific tariffs - Rare in developed countries but sometimes occurs in developing countries as a way to generate government revenue ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ] --- # Tariff Schedule .center[ ![:scale 40%](../images/tariffscheduleflax.png) .smallest[ U.S. tariff schedule on imported woven flax fabrics, [Harmonized Tariff Schedule](https://hts.usitc.gov/current), United States International Trade Commission Chapter 53, p. 53-4 ]] --- # Tariff History .center[ ![:scale 70%](../images/worldtarifftrends.png) ] --- # Tariff History .center[ ![:scale 70%](../images/ustariffhistory.jpg) ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Effects of an Import Tariff in a Small Country --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smallest[ - To analyze effects of a tariff (on imports), need to compare two cases: 1. Effect of a tariff in a .hi[“small” country] - “Small” `\(\implies\)` its domestic market is too small to affect world prices - Effectively, it is a .hi-purple[price-taker]: it can import as much as it wants and not drive up the price 2. Effect of a tariff in a .hi[“large” nation] - “Large” `\(\implies\)` changes in the country’s domestic market *can* affect world prices ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](../images/bigvssmallcountry.jpg) ] ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-1-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-2-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-3-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium - Autarky price: 10¢/lb, 10 billion lbs exchanged within Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-4-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium - Autarky price: 10¢/lb, 10 billion lbs exchanged within Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-5-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(10-0)($0.20-$0.10) = $0.5 billion - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium - Autarky price: 10¢/lb, 10 billion lbs exchanged within Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-6-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(10-0)($0.20-$0.10) = $0.5 billion - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium - .red[Producer surplus] = p* - WTA - Autarky price: 10¢/lb, 10 billion lbs exchanged within Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-7-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(10-0)($0.20-$0.10) = $0.5 billion - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium - .red[Producer surplus] = p* - WTA - = 0.5(10-0)($0.10-$0.00) = $0.5 billion - Autarky price: 10¢/lb, 10 billion lbs exchanged within Belgium ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-8-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in Belgium - .hi-blue[Domestic Demand] for sugar in Belgium - .hi-red[Domestic Supply] of sugar in Belgium - Suppose Belgium opens up to international trade - .hi-orange[World Supply] of sugar at 4¢/lb ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-9-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - At 4¢/lb: - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 16 bn lbs ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-10-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - At 4¢/lb: - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 16 bn lbs - .red[Belgian producers] will produce 4 bn lbs ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-11-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - At 4¢/lb: - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 16 bn lbs - .red[Belgian producers] will produce 4 bn lbs - Belgium will .orange[import] 12 bn lbs from the .orange[rest of the world] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-12-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under international trade: - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(16-0)($0.20-$0.04) = $1.280 billion ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-13-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under international trade: - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(16-0)($0.20-$0.04) = $1.280 billion - .red[Producer surplus] = p* - WTA - = 0.5(4-0)($0.04-$0.00) = $0.080 billion ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-14-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under international trade: - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(16-0)($0.20-$0.04) = $1.280 billion - .red[Producer surplus] = p* - WTA - = 0.5(4-0)($0.04-$0.00) = $0.080 billion - Trade benefits .blue[Belgian consumers] at expense of .red[Belgian sugar producers] - But gain is much bigger than loss! ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-15-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-16-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-17-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .smallest[ - We can trace Belgium’s import demand from the world based on the world price - Note at a price of ¢10 there is no import demand, all sugar can be produced in Belgium ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-18-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-19-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .smallest[ - We can trace Belgium’s import demand from the world based on the world price - Note at a price of ¢10 there is no import demand, all sugar can be produced in Belgium - We have been assuming the world supply of sugar is perfectly elastic at 4¢ - Sets equilibrium amount of imports in Belgium, 12 bn lbs imported ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose the government levies a 4¢/lb .hi-purple[tariff] on sugar imports ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-20-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose the government levies a 4¢/lb .hi-purple[tariff] on sugar imports - At new domestic sugar price of 8¢/lb ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-21-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose the government levies a 4¢/lb .hi-purple[tariff] on sugar imports - At new domestic sugar price of 8¢/lb - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 12 bn lbs (less than before) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-22-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose the government levies a 4¢/lb .hi-purple[tariff] on sugar imports - At new domestic sugar price of 8¢/lb - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 12 bn lbs (less than before) - .red[Belgian producers] will produce 8 bn lbs (more than before) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-23-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose the government levies a 4¢/lb .hi-purple[tariff] on sugar imports - At new domestic sugar price of 8¢/lb - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 12 bn lbs (less than before) - .red[Belgian producers] will produce 8 bn lbs (more than before) - Belgium will .orange[import] 4 bn lbs from the .orange[rest of the world] (less than before) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-24-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose the government levies a 4¢/lb .hi-purple[tariff] on sugar imports - At new domestic sugar price of 8¢/lb - .blue[Belgian consumers] want to consume 12 bn lbs (less than before) - .red[Belgian producers] will produce 8 bn lbs (more than before) - Belgium will .orange[import] 4 bn lbs from the .orange[rest of the world] (less than before) - Tariff is a tax, so government earns revenue: - 4 bn lbs $\times $ 0.04/lb = $0.160 bn ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-25-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under the tariff: - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(12-0)($0.20-$0.08) = $0.720 billion - Less than before (free trade) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-26-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under the tariff: - .blue[Consumer surplus] = WTP - p* - = 0.5(12-0)($0.20-$0.08) = $0.720 billion - Less than before (free trade) - .red[Producer surplus] = p* - WTA - = 0.5(8-0)($0.08-$0.00) = $0.320 billion - More than before (free trade) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-27-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under the tariff: - Two new sources of market inefficiency created, .b[“deadweight loss (DWL)”] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-28-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under the tariff: - Two new sources of market inefficiency created, .b[“deadweight loss (DWL)”] 1. Inefficient domestic production (cheaper for foreigners to produce sugar) - 0.5(8-4)($0.08-$0.04) = $0.080 Billion ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-29-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Under the tariff: - Two new sources of market inefficiency created, .b[“deadweight loss (DWL)”] 1. Inefficient domestic production (cheaper for foreigners to produce sugar) - 0.5(8-4)($0.08-$0.04) = $0.080 Billion 2. Lost gains from exchange (consumers wanted to buy more from world) - 0.5(16-12)($0.08-$0.04) = $0.080 Billion ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-30-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-31-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-32-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .smallest[ - Can also see this in the import market - Decline of imports at higher price in Belgium - Size of DWL in import market = sum of both DWL triangles in Belgian market ($0.160 bn) ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smallest[ - Domestic consequences of tariff: 1. .blue[Decrease in consumer surplus]: - $0.720 bn-$1.280 bn = .blue[-$0.460 bn] 2. .red[Increase in producer surplus]: - $0.320 bn-$0.080 bn = .red[$0.240 bn] 3. .green[Government tax revenue]: - .green[$0.160 bn] 4. .b[Deadweight losses] - $-0.080 bn - $0.080 bn = .b[-$0.160 bn] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-33-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Small Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Domestic consequences of tariff: - A $240m gain to a small group of domestic sugar producers at a $460m expense to consumers - Concentrated benefit, dispersed cost each consumer pays $0.04/lb more for sugar - Harm to foreigners: hurts exporters and consumers in other countries from lost trade ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-34-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Tariff Effects in a Large Country --- # Large Countries in International Trade .pull-left[ .smallest[ - A .hi-purple[“large country”] has a sufficiently large domestic demand to affect international prices - The decrease in domestic demand from an import tariff (from higher import price) is sufficiently large to .hi-purple[lower the world price of the good] - This is called the .hi[“terms of trade effect”] of a tariff - can provide a *benefit* to domestic country - harms foreign exporters due to lower world price ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](../images/bigvssmallcountry.jpg) ] ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Consider, for example, the sugar market in the U.S. - Autarky price: 10¢/lb, 10 billion lbs exchanged within U.S. ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-35-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose U.S. opens up to international trade - .hi-orange[World Supply] of sugar at 4¢/lb: ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-36-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Suppose U.S. opens up to international trade - .hi-orange[World Supply] of sugar at 4¢/lb: - .blue[U.S. consumers] want to consume 16 bn lbs - .red[U.S. producers] will produce 4 bn lbs - U.S. will .orange[import] 12 bn lbs from the .orange[rest of the world] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-37-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-38-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-39-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .quitesmall[ - We can trace U.S.’s import demand from the world based on the world price - Because U.S. is a large country, the world supply curve (exports from other countries) to U.S. is *upward* sloping - sufficiently high demand from U.S. stimulates production abroad for export to U.S. - Imagine autarky equilibrium price in exporting countries is 2¢; once they can get higher price in U.S., start exporting - Sets equilibrium amount of imports in U.S., 12 bn lbs imported at 4¢ ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .quitesmall[ - Now suppose U.S. imposes a 4¢/lb tariff on imported sugar - Increase in costs to world sugar exporters decreases world export supply by 4¢/lb - New equilibrium is for U.S. to import 6 bn lbs at 7¢/lb - But 4¢/lb of the imports are paid to U.S. government as tariffs - Exporters to U.S. recieve *net price* (after taxes) of 3¢/lb - Important: raise in price to U.S. consumers is less than the full 4¢/lb! - Tariff on the massive U.S. market has lowered the *world* price of sugar because of decreased world supply, the .hi-purple[terms of trade effect] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-40-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Now suppose U.S. imposes a 4¢/lb tariff on imported sugar - Due to the terms of trade effect, world price of sugar will fall from less U.S. demand (to 3¢/lb) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-41-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Now suppose U.S. imposes a 4¢/lb tariff on imported sugar - Due to the terms of trade effect, world price of sugar will fall from less U.S. demand (to 3¢/lb) - The 4¢/lb is levied on this *new, lower* world price of sugar, raising price of sugar in U.S. to 7¢/lb ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-42-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - At new domestic price of 7¢/lb: - .blue[U.S. consumers] want to consume 13 bn lbs (less than before) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-43-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - At new domestic price of 7¢/lb: - .blue[U.S. consumers] want to consume 13 bn lbs (less than before) - .red[U.S. producers] will produce 7 bn lbs (more than before) ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-44-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - At new domestic price of 7¢/lb: - .blue[U.S. consumers] want to consume 13 bn lbs (less than before) - .red[U.S. producers] will produce 7 bn lbs (more than before) - U.S. will .orange[import] 6 bn lbs from .orange[rest of the world] (less than before) - Note the changes are not as much as it was to the small country - U.S. “market power” forces down world price ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-45-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Loss to .blue[U.S. consumer surplus] (but less than for small country) - Gain to .red[U.S. producer surplus] (but less than for small country) - .purple[Transfer of CS to PS] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-46-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Tariff will collect revenue for government - 4¢/lb `\(\times\)` 6 bn lbs = $0.240 bn ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-47-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Tariff will collect revenue for government - 4¢/lb `\(\times\)` 6 bn lbs = .green[$0.240 bn] - DWLs from productive and consumption inefficiencies - 2 `\(\times\)` $-0.045 bn = .b[-$0.090 bn] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-48-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Tariff will collect revenue for government - 4¢/lb `\(\times\)` 6 bn lbs = .green[$0.240 bn] - DWLs from productive and consumption inefficiencies - 2 `\(\times\)` $-0.045 bn = .b[-$0.090 bn] - But: .hi-purple[gain in tariff revenue exceeds inefficiency (DWL)!] - .hi-purple[Tariff brings a net increase in U.S. national welfare!] ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-49-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-50-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-51-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .smallest[ - Area .hi-purple[D] is the .hi-purple[Terms of trade] gain for U.S. (loss to world) due to tariff - U.S. deadweight loss (A+B) `\(<\)` U.S. tariff revenue (.green[C]+.purple[D]) - Foreign loses deadweight loss (F) from lost export opportunities ] --- # Import Tariff Effects in a Large Country .pull-left[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-52-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-53-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .smallest[ - Welfare changes: - To US: (.green[C]+.purple[D])-(A+B), net gain! - To Rest of World: -(.purple[D]+E), net loss - Whole World: .green[C]-(A+B+E), net loss - A “beggar thy neighbor” approach to increasing national welfare ] --- # Big vs. Small Comparisons .smaller[ - Both countries start out with same world price, imports, domestic demand and supply - With free trade: | Country | `\(p^*\)` | `\(q^*\)` | Domestic `\(q\)` | .orange[Imports] | .blue[CS] | .red[PS] | .green[Tax Revenue] | .b[DWL] | |---------|------:|------:|----:|--------:|---:|---:|---:|---:| | Small (Belgium) | $0.04 | 16 bn | 4 bn | 12 bn | $1.280 bn | $0.080 bn | $0 | $0 | | Large (U.S.) | $0.04 | 16 bn | 4 bn | 12 bn | $1.280 bn | $0.080 bn | $0 | $0 | ] -- .smaller[ - With same 4¢ tariff on imports: | Country | `\(p^*\)` | `\(q^*\)` | Domestic `\(q\)` | .orange[Imports] | `\(\Delta\)` .blue[CS] | `\(\Delta\)` .red[PS] | .green[Tax Revenue] | .b[DWL] | |---------|------:|------:|----:|--------:|---:|---:|---:|---:| | Small (Belgium) | $0.08 | 12 bn | 8 bn | 4 bn | -$0.560 bn | $0.240 bn | $0.160 bn | -$0.160 bn | | Large (U.S.) | $0.07 | 13 bn | 7 bn | 6 bn | -$0.435 bn | $0.035 bn | $0.240 bn | -$0.090 bn | ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Optimal Tariff Theory --- # Optimal Tariff Theory .pull-left[ .smallest[ - For a large country, a tariff decreases volume of trade but improves country’s terms of trade - Gain of tariff revenue (.green[C]+.purple[D]) - Loss of deadweight loss (A+B) - Net effect is a slight increase in (big) country’s welfare - Note tariffs always are a net harm to a small nation! - Thus, there exists some .hi[optimal tariff] `\(\tau > 0\)` that maximizes net gains from tradeoff between terms of trade improvements against decline in trade ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ] --- # Optimal Tariff Theory (in a Large Country) .pull-left[ .smallest[ - `\(\tau = 0\)`: free trade - For low levels of `\(\tau\)`, terms of trade gain exceed deadweight loss - (.green[C]+.purple[D]) > (A+B) - For high levels of `\(\tau\)`, deadweight loss exceeds terms of trade gain - (.green[C]+.purple[D]) < (A+B) - Extremely high levels of `\(\tau\)` will close off trade completely - Some optimal `\(\tau^{\star}\)` that maximizes welfare gain to importer ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-54-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Optimal Tariff Theory vs. the Real World .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Economic theory shows the .hi-purple[theoretical possibility] of how tariffs might increase national welfare - Regardless, tariffs harm welfare of trading partners (exporting countries) - Politically and practically, trading partners might .hi[retaliate] against tariffs with their own tariffs - Might degenerate into a .hi-purple[trade war] where potential gains from trade are lost ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # The Effective Rate of Protection --- # The Effective Rate of Protection .pull-left[ .smaller[ - .hi-purple[How much do tariffs protect domestic industry?] - Seems logical to just count the percent an *ad valorem* tariff raises price over free trade price - This is the .hi[nominal rate of protection]: the % increase in price - e.g. a 50% *ad valorem* tariff raises price 50% - for specific tariffs, divide `\(\frac{\text{price with tariff}}{\text{price without tariff}}\)` ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Two problems with nominal rate of protection: 1. If the country is “large”, part of the tariff’s effect will be to *lower foreign export prices* rather than just raise domestic prices 2. Tariffs may have different effects on different *stages* of production for a good ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection .pull-left[ .smaller[ - Better to think about the .hi[effective rate of protection] as the percent change in .hi-purple[domestic value added] - .content-box-green[ .hi-green[Example]: Suppose **cars** sell on world market for $8,000, and **car parts** sell for $6,000. If a country buys car parts and assembles them into cars, the .hi-purple[domestic value added] is: $$\$8,000-\$6,000=\$2,000$$ ] ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/car.png) ![:scale 100%](../images/carparts.jpeg) ] ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection: Example .pull-left[ .quitesmall[ - Suppose .blue[Home] wants to develop a domestic **auto assembly** industry - .pink[Domestic value] added from .green[imports] is: $$\$8,000-\color{green}{\$6,000}=\color{red}{\$2,000}$$ - .blue[Home] places a **25% tariff** on **imported cars**, raising the price of cars in .blue[Home] to $10,000 - .pink[Domestic value] added from .green[imports] is: $$\$10,000-\color{green}{\$6,000}=\color{red}{\$4,000}$$ - .hi[Domestic value added] changes by: $$\frac{\$4,000-\$2,000}{\$2,000} \times 100 = 100\%$$ ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-55-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection: Example .pull-left[ .quitesmall[ - Suppose .blue[Home] instead wants to develop a domestic **car parts** industry - .pink[Domestic value] added from .green[imports] is: $$\$8,000-\color{green}{\$6,000}=\color{red}{\$2,000}$$ - .blue[Home] places a **25% tariff** on **imported car _parts_**, raising the price of car parts in .blue[Home] to $7,500 - .pink[Domestic value added] for **car parts manufacturers** is: $$\$\color{red}{\$7,500}$$ - Changes by: $$\frac{\$7,500-\$6,000}{\$6,000} \times 100% = 25\%$$ ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-56-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection: Example .pull-left[ .quitesmall[ - Suppose .blue[Home] instead wants to develop a domestic **car parts** industry - .pink[Domestic value] added from .green[imports] is: $$\$8,000-\color{green}{\$6,000}=\color{red}{\$2,000}$$ - What about for **assemblers** of cars? - .pink[Domestic value added] for **car assemblers** is: $$\$8,000-\color{green}{\$7,500}=\color{red}{\$500}$$ - Changes by: $$\frac{\$500-\$2,000}{\$2,000} \times 100% = -75\%$$ ] ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-57-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection: Example .pull-left[ - We can see that the .hi-purple[structure of tariffs] often impact different stages of the production process differently - Here, a tariff on car parts gave 25% more protection to domestic car parts producers, at the expense of a 75% loss to domestic car assemblers ] .pull-right[ <img src="2.1-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-58-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # The Effective Rate of Protection .pull-left[ .smaller[ - In general, we see that effective rate of protection `\(\neq\)` nominal tariff rate - May be higher or lower, or even negative - Tariffs on foreign inputs generate *negative* effective rates of protection, and tariffs on final products generate *positive* eeffective rates of protection for a country’s domestic industry ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](../images/tradebarriers.jpg) ] ]