Now that we know the major models and tools of trade policy, we want to examine what are the best arguments for and against free trade
To do this, we dive into the history of trade and the intellectual history of trade arguments
We will examine and discuss (on the discussion board) some papers about the development of trading institutions
Bring it up to modern arguments against free trade, industrial policy, and then politics
“Globalization” is not a new idea
Ancient Empires in Rome, China, India, North Africa, linked by “international” trade
Why was feudalism such a stable equilibrium for about 1,000 years?
How, when, and why did countries transition out of this equilibrium?
Fall of Roman Empire and its dependencies by invasions of Germanic, Central Asian, later Scandinavian tribes
Lots of sources of violence: invaders, bandits, local disputes/feuds without central authority
Patronage: weaker individuals pledge themselves to strongmen (lords) who protect them from violence, dispense justice, resolve disputes, etc
Most powerful warlords own large tracts of land that they can control
Feudalism: most people who who occupy but don't own land hold it as tenants from sovereign in exchange for military (or other) service
Wealth and power determined almost entirely by land-ownership
Lords own manors or estates
Landowning elite have military power
Crystalized into a very formal and ritualized system of oaths of fealty to lords
Reputation and honor are extremely valuable and depreciable assets
Person would pledge homage to their superior, to literally "become his man" (homme)
Lord would provide protection and justice in exchange for knight-service
A political-military hierarchy that matched the landowner-tenant ownership hierarchy
Lesser lords were vassals to their liege lord to whom they owe loyalty and service, all the way up to the monarch
Nearly the entirety of Medieval life took place on the lord's manor or fief
Subsistence agriculture by sharecropping tenants
Tenants pay feudal dues to their lord
No separation between political, economic, social, religious spheres of life
Lord of the manor is boss, political ruler, judge, policeman, godfather, sometimes religious leader
All institutions are personal and partial, no separate existence of organizations from person
Farmer wants to farm the landowner's land and generate some surplus
Farmer and Landowner must write a contract to agree on how to divide the surplus
One extreme solution:
Farmer pays a fixed fee up front, once paid, the farmer keeps all surplus
Would have to be high enough to be worthwhile to the landlord
Problems with this solution:
A risk-sharing agreement: worker pays a smaller (or no) upfront fee, and surplus output is shared between parties somehow
Risk of a bad harvest is shared by the farmer and the landowner
Farmer has an incentive to underreport to landlord how much surplus they produce, effectively "stealing" more than their share
Farmer is effectively taxed (50%, in this example) on their output
A tradeoff between risk-sharing and tax on effort/incentives to shirk
Most real world sharecropping today is a mixture of fixed and variable components
Serfs and freemen "worked for all" while a knight or baron "fought for all" and a churchman "prayed for all"; thus everyone had a place
Forged in the crucible of a breakdown of empires and constant threat of violence and invasion
Feudalism is primarily about stability and custom, preserving the social order, minimizing violence
The last thing it's okay with is innovation, competition, experimentation, and rocking the boat
The one thing everyone shares is religion
Catholic Church is dominant, both in Medieval ethics and politics, the only "international" institution
All actions, exchanges, social and political power are justified as moral (Christian), legitimate, and upholding ancient privileges and customs
"[T]he medieval way of determining the terms of exchange was by custom, usage, and law, not by negotiation between traders. The division of labor was well developed by the Middle Ages, and there was a corollary exchange of products and services among specialized workers. But the use of custom and law to set the terms of trade was as fundamental to the medieval economy as the unity of its political and economic institutions," (p.38).
Rosenberg, Nathan and L.E. Birdzell, Jr, (1986) How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World
"Exchange was also usually compulsory, in that the great majority of artisans and agricultural workers were obligated to supply their products and services on terms dictated by custom or law. Agricultural workers were bound to the land in a system of serfdom, a hereditary status assumed at birth, and they had no right to select a more attractive occupation. Townspeople were not given much more choice of occupation, for having a trade...depended on an apprenticeship, usually arranged by one's father...A member of the guild had to work and sell on the guild terms; there was no right to decline business at the fixed rates," (p.38).
Rosenberg, Nathan and L.E. Birdzell, Jr, (1986) How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World
"The ideology of the system was epitomized in the phrases "just price" and "just wage." Prices and wages expressed a moral judgment of worth. Supply and demand were morally irrelevant...it was mainly in time of famine or siege that prices forced their way into [equating supply and demand]," (p.38).
Rosenberg, Nathan and L.E. Birdzell, Jr, (1986) How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World
Virginia Postrel
"[I]f every voluntary experiment must answer the question, 'Are you going to affect the way I live?' with a no, there can be no experiments, no new communities, no realized dreams. A city, an economy, or a culture is, despite the best efforts of stasists, fundamentally a 'natural' system. As a whole, it is beyond anyone’s control. Any individual effort at improvement changes not just the particular target but the broader system. In the process, there may be progress, but there will also be disruptions, adjustments, and losers," (p.204).
Postrel, Virginia, (1998) The Future and Its Enemies
Virginia Postrel
"Stasist institutions shift the burden of proof from the people who want to block new ideas to those who want to experiment. Such institutions seek not simply to compensate for or mitigate extreme side effects but, rather, to treat any change as suspect," (p.204).
Postrel, Virginia, (1998) The Future and Its Enemies
"There is a story, repeated by a number of Roman writers, that a man - characteristically unnamed - invented un-breakable glass and demonstrated it to Tiberius in anticipation of a great reward. The emperor asked the inventor whether anyone shared his secret and was assured that there was no one else; whereupon his head was promptly removed, lest, said Tiberius, gold be reduced to the value of mud," (147).
Finley, Moses I, (1965), "Technical Innovation and Economic Progress in the Ancient World," Economic History Review 18: 29–45
"Thou aimest high, master Lee. Consider thou what the invention could do to my poor subjects. It would assuredly bring to them ruin by depriving them of employment, thus making them beggars," (quoted in Acemoglu and Robinson 2012, pp. 182-183).
Towns are dominated by urban craft guilds
Another feudal group with major economic and political power
Essentially cartels that restrict entry into trades
Alliance with monarchs (exclusive privileges in exchange for tax revenues)
Ogilvie, Sheilagh, (2014), "The Economics of Guilds," Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(4): 169-192
Greif, Avner, (1989), "Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on Maghribi Traders," Journal of Economic History 49(4): 857-882.
Greif, Avner, Paul Milgrom, and Barry R Weingast, (1994), "Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild," Journal of Political Economy 102(4): 745-776
First Crusade 1095, goal of retaking the Holy Land from Arabs
Lost Jerusalem to Saladin in 1187, never recaptured
At least 9 crusades by 1291
"Outremer" Crusader kingdoms in Levant for 200 years
Last (in some form) until 1300
Outlet for peasants, nobles, merchants, etc. fleeing hardships of Europe
"International" institutions
Increase European interaction with rest of the world via Arabs (who trade with India and China)
(Re)discovery of classical philosophy, mathematics, literature, art from Arabs (who retained it from Ancient Greece and Rome)
Thomas Hobbes
1588-1679
"In [the state of nature], there is no place for Industry; because the fruit thereof is uncertain; and consequently no Culture of the Earth...no Knowledge of the face of the Earth; no account of Time; no Arts; no Letters; no Society; and which is worst of all, continuall feare, and danger of violent death; And the life of man, solitary, poore, nasty, brutish, and short, (Ch. XVIII).
Hobbes, Thomas, 1651, Leviathan: Or the Matter, Forme and Power of a Commonwealth, Ecclesiasticall and Civil
Thomas Hobbes
1588-1679
"For the Lawes of Nature (as Justice, Equity, Modesty, Mercy, and (in summe) Doing To Others, As Wee Would Be Done To,) if themselves, without the terrour of some Power, to cause them to be observed, are contrary to our naturall Passions, that carry us to Partiality, Pride, Revenge, and the like. And Covenants, without the Sword, are but Words, and of no strength to secure a man at all, (Ch. XVIII).
Hobbes, Thomas, 1651, Leviathan: Or the Matter, Forme and Power of a Commonwealth, Ecclesiasticall and Civil
Nash equilibrium: everyone defects!
Socially optimal equilibrium: everyone cooperates
Hobbes' insight: no individual has an incentive to cooperate when everyone defects!
The State is our commitment device
Citizens (in principle) sign a social contract, i.e. a "constitution" that deliberately restricts their liberties
In each of our interests to give up some liberties that restrict the liberties of others (e.g. theft, violence)
In exchange, we empower the State as our agent to punish those of us that fail to uphold the social contract
Max Weber
1864-1920
"[A] State is a human community that (successfully) claims the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force within a given territory."
Weber, Max, 1919, Politics as a Vocation
James Madison
1751-1836
"If men were angels, no government would be necessary. If angels were to govern men, neither external nor internal controls on government would be necessary. In framing a government which is to be administered by men over men, the great difficulty lies in this: you must first enable the government to control the governed; and in the next place oblige it to control itself," (Federalist 51).
1788, The Federalist Papers
"Talk is cheap"
With perfect information, promises or threats will not change equilibrium if they are not credible
Strategy must be incentive-compatible, if game reaches the relevant decision, it must be in your interest to carry out your promise or threat!
Threats and promises can be credible with commitment
A commitment changes the game in a way that forces you to carry out your promise or threat
Odysseus and the Sirens by John William Waterhouse, Scene from Homer's The Odyssey
Odysseus and the Sirens by John William Waterhouse, Scene from Homer's The Odyssey
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, (1990), "The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs," (Economics and Politics*2(1): 1-23
Rulers (kings, queens, emperor, lords) face certain incentives:
Often granted cities and merchants privileges and exemptions from feudal duties
Trade requires peace & stable property rights
After a ruler promises to protect trade, incentives arise for him/her to renege on promise!
Can trade exist with cours that are partial to local merchants over foreign merchants?
Medieval guilds, leagues of city-states
Coalition and reputation system
Merchant law
We often think of Medieval guilds as just monopolies or cartels meant to restrict trade
But in a way they also promoted trade
Most famous guild: Hanseatic League (German “Hansa”) of Northern Europe
Guilds were administrative bodies
Ability to regulate trade within local region
Guilds had chapters in each city, could gain access to all guild privileges abroad
Monitored and provided information about merchant activity
Guilds allowed merchants to coordinate collective action in punishing transgressors
A free rider problem in punishment:
Violating merchants would have their privileges revoked, or be expelled from guild
Untrustworthy rulers would be boycotted by entire guild across Europe
“It was announced that any disobedience, whether by a town or an individual, was to be punished by perpetual exclusion from the Hansa”
Long distance international trade took place in fairs, like the Champagne Fair
Transactions at fairs: transfer of goods in exchange for promissory note to be paid at next fair
No established commercial law or State enforcement of contracts
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23
Essentially playing1 an infinitely repeated Prisoners' Dilemma2
Game theory of repeated games
1 Where Buyer can be a consumer or another firm
2 "Infinitely" = game does not have a clear final turn.
Each player will always Cooperate iff: ∞-payoff stream of (C,C)>payoff of 1 (D,C)+∞-payoff stream of (D,D)
If two specific merchants repeatedly interact, honesty can be sustained by trigger strategies
Then why need a legal system?
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23
Milgrom, North, and Weingast (1990) model these interactions as a multi-stage repeated game (p.11)
If costs of asking judge are not too high, and if players are sufficiently patient, can sustain honest trade
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23
International merchants can't depend on weak and biased States to enforce international contracts!
Merchants adopted their own "laws" and best practices to minimize transaction costs
For-profit merchant courts emerge to settle disputes and enforce international contracts
Developed contract law and advanced legal instruments - debt, credit, loans, equity contracts
This is a major basis of international commercial law today!
Benson, Bruce, 1989. "The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law," Southern Economic Journal 55(3): 644-661
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, (1990), "The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs," (Economics and Politics*2(1): 1-23
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |