Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
Princeton economist that argued comparative advantage is not an “infallable principle” for commercial policy
Argued that some industries might warrant permanent protection
Main argument hinges on increasing returns to scale (decreasing cost industry)
Graham, Frank D, 1923, “Some Aspects of Protection Further Considered,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
“protection to manufactures may advantageously be continued much longer than would seem adequate to cover the infant stage, whether or not the industry could maintain itself without such aid,” (p.200).
“[I]t may be to a country’s economic advantage to protect an industry which could not grow up or survive without protection and which never will be able to survive without it, an industry which has no comparative advantage when the protective duty is first levied nor ever attains one under it,” (pp.202-203).
Graham, Frank D, 1923, “Some Aspects of Protection Further Considered,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
Graham’s numerical example (essentially):
Suppose two countries have two industries:
Suppose labor is the main input in each industry
Graham, Frank D, 1923, “Some Aspects of Protection Further Considered,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Country A specializes in agriculture
More labor allocated to agriculture, lowers MPL in agriculture
Less labor allocated to manufacturing, also lowers MPL in manufacturing
Consumers in A can consume less agriculture and less manufacturing goods
Country B specializes in manufacturing
Less labor allocated to agriculture, raises MPL in agriculture
More labor allocated to manufacturing, also raises MPL in manufacturing
Consumers in B can consume more agriculture and more manufacturing goods
Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
“The final result of the specialization is to bring about a situation in which the citizens of the [country specializing in agriculture] get less reward for their efforts than if they had never carried on international trade at all,” (p.207).
Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
“The conclusion that [the] country under the conditions assumed [specializing in agriculture] must lose by free trade is inevitable...[instead it requires] advantageous permanent protection [since the country is better off in autarky, or with less trade, it is] economically benefitted by protection and may do well to keep it indefinitely,” (p.208).
Graham, Frank D, 1923, “Some Aspects of Protection Further Considered,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
“It may well be disadvantageous for a nation to concentrate in production of commodities of increasing cost despite a comparative advantage in those lines; it will the more probably be disadvantageous to do so if the world demand for goods produced at decreasing cost is growing in volume more rapidly than that for goods produced at increasing cost,” (p.210).
Graham, Frank D, 1923, “Some Aspects of Protection Further Considered,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Frank D. Graham
1890—1949
“There is no reason for supposing that this would happen,” (p.210).
Graham, Frank D, 1923, “Some Aspects of Protection Further Considered,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Frank H. Knight
1885-1972
Counter against Graham’s “ingenious” but “fallacious” argument
Took major issue with a footnote in Graham:
“The reasoning in the text simply assumes that a decreasing [average] cost is obtained by an expansion of the production of [manufacturing]; whether the cause of it be external or internal economies is immaterial to the theory, though it would, of course, affect the degree of its applicability,” (p.204n).
Frank H. Knight
1885-1972
“If competition is effective, the size of the production unit will tend to grow until either no further economies are obtainable, or there is only one establishment left and the idnustry is a monopoly...When all establishments have been brought to the efficient size, variation in total output is a matter of changing their number, in which no technical economies are involved...an increase in the output of a commodity must increase its cost of production unless the industry is, or becomes, a monopoly,” (p.597)
Knight, Frank H, 1924, “Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Social Cost,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 38 (4): 582–606.
Frank H. Knight
1885-1972
“The rejoinder to [this] argument is the doctrine of ‘external economies’ [but] this surely rests upon a misconception. External economies in one [firm] are internal economies in some other, within the industry. Any branch or stage in the creation of a product which offers continuously a chance for [internal] economies [of scale] with increase in the scale of operations must eventuate either in monopoly or in leaving the tendency behind and establishing the normal relation of increasing cost with increasing size,” (p.597)
Knight, Frank H, 1924, “Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Social Cost,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 38 (4): 582–606.
Frank H. Knight
1885-1972
“What Professor Graham has to do to establish his theoretica lposition is to show that...industry really operates under decreasing cost, without tending toward monopoly...if one can make his assumptions in regard to decreasing cost, his conclusion is correct. [However] to vindicate decreasing costs in the sense required, it must be shown that there are, or may be, industries, in a condition of stable competition, in which no producer already engaged could decrease his real costs by expandind his output at the expense of other producers, and yet in which real costs would be decreased all around by new producers entering the industry in competition with those already there.” (p.331)
Frank H. Knight
1885-1972
“These inevitable sources of increasing cost must be more than offset by some kind of purely ‘external’ economies in organization. In spite of the weight of authority which may be cited for such economies [i.e. Marshall], I have never succeeded in picturing in them in my mind, or finding any convincing reason to believe they exist; and the hypothetical examples cited by Professor Graham...has not assisted me in doing so. I cannot believe such conditions general enough to justify a special law in economic theory, or a special provision in tariff legislation,” (p.331).
Jacob Viner
1892-1970
“These extraordinary results are the consequence, and wholly the consequence, of value-theory reasoning, implicit or explicit in Graham's argument, which is either unambiguously erroneous or is of very limited practical significance,” (p.478).
Viner, Jacob, 1937, Studies in The Theory of International Trade
Jacob Viner
1892-1970
“[If the external economies are pecuniary] then they are not real national economies and nothing is lost to the country when they disappear,” (p.480).
Viner, Jacob, 1937, Studies in The Theory of International Trade
Jacob Viner
1892-1970
“A concievable case for protection on the basis of the existence of external economies in an industry which from the individual producer’s point of view is at a comparative disadvantage in costs can be made out, therefore, only where these external economies are (a) dependent on the size of the national and not the world industry and (b) are technological rather than pecuniary, or if pecuniary, are not at the expense of domestic sellers or services or materials to the industry. The scope for application of the argument is extremely limited, especially as it seems difficult even to suggest plausible hypothetical cases of the existence of genuine technological external economies...[Graham’s increasing returns argument for protectionism is] little more than a theoretical curiosity” (pp.480-481).
Viner, Jacob, 1937, Studies in The Theory of International Trade
Economies of scale come in two flavors:
Internal economies: firm-level features that improve a firm's productivity, often leading to market power for that firm
External economies: industry-wide features that spill over to the productivity all firms in the industry
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“...are dependent on the resources of individual houses of business engaged in [the industry], on their organization and the efficiency of their management,” (p.220).
“...are dependent on the general development of the industry [some of which] depend on the aggregate volume of production of the kind in the neighborhood while others again, especially those connected with the growth of knowledge and the progress of the arts, depend chiefly on the aggregate volume of production in the whole civilized world,” (p.220).
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“The most important of these result from the growth of correlated branches of industry which mutually assist one another, perhaps being concentrated in the same localities, but anyhow availing themselves of the modern facilities for communication offered by steam transport, by the telegraph and by the printing press,” (p.264).
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics
It must be proven that there are genuine external and technological economies of scale in order for it to make sense to abandon free trade & protect a domestic industry with increasing returns
A search for sources of increasing returns
Rivalrous | Nonrival | |
---|---|---|
Excludable | PRIVATE GOODS | COMMON RESOURCES |
(Houses, Jeans) | (Fisheries, Environment) | |
Nonexcludable | CLUB GOODS | PUBLIC GOODS |
(Wifi, Cable TV) | (Asteroid Defense) |
Thomas Jefferson
(1743-1826)
"He who receives an idea from me, receives instruction himself without lessening mine; as he who lights his taper at mine, receives light without darkening me. That ideas should freely spread from one to another over the globe, for the moral and mutual instruction of man, and improvement of his condition, seems to have been peculiarly and benevolently designed by nature, when she made them, like fire, expansible over all space, without lessening their density in any point, and like the air in which we breathe, move, and have our physical being, incapable of confinement or exclusive appropriation."
Jefferson, Thomas, 13 Aug 1813, "Letter to Isaac MacPherson,"
Thomas Macaulay
(1800-1859)
"It is then on men whose profession is literature, and whose private means are not ample, that you must rely for a supply of valuable books. Such men must be remunerated for their literary labour...It is desirable that we should have a supply of good books; we cannot have such a supply unless men of letters are liberally remunerated, and the least objectionable way of remunerating them is by means of copyright...The system of copyright has great advantages, and great disadvantages...Copyright is monopoly, and produces all the effects which the general voice of mankind attributes to monopoly...Monopoly is an evil...For the sake of the good we must submit to the evil; but the evil ought not to last a day longer than is necessary for the purpose of securing the good..."
Macaulay, Thomas, 1841 Parliamentay speech against Serjeant Talfourd's 1841 Copyright Bill
William Nordhaus
(1941-)
Economics Nobel 2018
"We conclude that [about 2.2%] of the social returns from technological advances over the 1948-2001 period was captured by producers, indicating that most of the benefits of technological change are passed on to consumers rather than captured by producers," (p.1)
Nordhaus, William, 2004, "Schumpeterian Profits in the American Economy: Theory and Measurement," NBER Working Paper 10433
For these economic reasons, patent (for ideas and inventions) and copyright (for expressions) laws exist
Grant temporary monopoly to holder in order to recover their fixed costs and provide incentive to undertake (risky and expensive) research/creativity
A utilitarian tradeoff between incentives and access
Some macroeconomic background:
Famous Solow (1956, 1957) model of economic growth
Endogenous growth theory seeks to endogenize that residual and explain growth by explaining how technology grows
Paul Romer and others
Paul Romer
(1955-)
Economics Nobel 2018
"Although other assumptions about secrecy and property rights could be considered, the equilibrium here is based on the assumption that anyone engaged in research has free access to the entire stock of knowledge. This is feasible because knowledge is a nonrival input. All researchers can take advantage of A at the same time," (p.S83).
Romer, Paul M, 1990, "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political EConomy 98(5-2): S71-S102
"[A] college-educated engineer working today and one working 100 years ago have the same human capital, which is measured in terms of years of forgone participation in the labor market. The engineer working today is more productive because he or she can take advantage of all of the additional knowledge accumulated as design problems were solved during the last 100 years," (pp. S83-S84).
Paul Romer
(1955-)
Economics Nobel 2018
"If all inputs were paid their value marginal product, the firm would suffer losses," (p.S76).
"There is little doubt that much of the value to society of any given innovation or discovery is not captured by the inventor, and any model that missed these spillovers would miss important elements of the growth process. Yet it is still the case that private, profit-maximizing agents make investments in the creation of new knowledge and that they earn a return on these investments by charging a price for the resulting goods that is greater than the marginal cost of producing the goods," (p.S90).
Romer, Paul M, 1990, "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political EConomy 98(5-2): S71-S102
The most obvious reason is that research has positive external effects. An additional design raises the productivity of all future individuals who do research, but because this benefit is nonexcludable, it is not reflected at all in the market price for designs. The second and an equally important reason...is that research produces an input that is purchased by a sector that engages in monopoly pricing. The markup of price over marginal cost forces a wedge between the marginal social product of an input used in this sector and its market compensation," (p.S96)
The most obvious reason is that research has positive external effects. An additional design raises the productivity of all future individuals who do research, but because this benefit is nonexcludable, it is not reflected at all in the market price for designs. The second and an equally important reason...is that research produces an input that is purchased by a sector that engages in monopoly pricing. The markup of price over marginal cost forces a wedge between the marginal social product of an input used in this sector and its market compensation," (p.S96)
"Within the confines of the model, the social optimum can be achieved by subsidizing the accumulation of A," (p.S97)
"A subsidy to physical capital accumulation may be a very poor substitute for direct subsidies that increase the incentive to undertake research. In the absence of feasible policies that can remove the divergence between the social and private returns to research, a second-best policy would be to subsidize the accumulation of total human capital," (p.S99)
If access to a large number of workers or consumers were all that mattered, having a large population would be a good substitute for trade with other nations. The model here suggests that what is important for growth is integration not into an economy with a large number of people but rather into one with a large amount of human capital, (p.S98)
"The most interesting positive implication of the model is that an economy with a larger total stock of human capital will experience faster growth. This finding suggests that free international trade can act to speed up growth. It also suggests a way to understand what it is about developed economies in the twentieth century that permitted rates of growth of income per capita that are unprecedented in human history. The model also suggests that low levels of human capital may help explain why growth is not observed in underdeveloped economies that are closed and why a less developed economy with a very large population can still benefit from economic integration with the rest of the world," (p.S99)
Joseph Stiglitz
1943—
Economics Nobel 2001
Because of their strange public good properties, there is a market failure in the production of ideas and entrepreneurship
Society underinvests in entrepreneurship and innovation
Government intervention via well-calibrated industrial policy can fix the market failure
“Industrial policies – in which governments intervene in the allocation of resources among sectors or favor some technologies over others – can help ”infant economies” learn. Learning may be more marked in some sectors (such as industrial manufacturing) than in others, and the benefits of that learning, including the institutional development required for success, may spill over to other economic activities,”
Stiglitz, Joseph, and Bruce C. Greenwald, 2014, Creating a Learning Society
Park Chung Hee
Ruler/President of South Korea
1961—1979
Korea in 1960: As poor as Africa
Today: As wealthy as Japan
Korean War: 1950-1953 devastates country
Military Coup in 1961, repressive dictatorship until 1979
From 1963-1973: exports grow almost 2,000%
Government sponsors and protects family-run industrial conglomerates (“chaebols”)
Frequent high-level corruption
Change in institutions: land reform for middle class (less for elites), more property rights, (export-oriented) markets
World class primary education
Ethic of discipline and hard work
Rode Japan's 1960s-1970s economic miracle (a nearby lower-wage country for Japanese manufacturing)
Government was very active in promoting South Korean business and export-focused industries
Moved away from import-substitution (the classic industrial policy recipe)!
Allowed international markets to dictate relative prices (did not try to distort markets)
Most policy measures were providing low-interest subsidized loans for exporting companies
Often lead(s) to corruption
Most corruption is usually growth-blocking by incumbents and elites
But in Korea a growth-promoting corruption!
Paul Krugman
1953—
Economics Nobel 2008
“The problem is that most of what a student is likely to read or hear about international economics is nonsense. What I want to argue in this paper is that the most important thing to teach our undergrads about trade is how to detect that nonsense. That is, our primary mission should be to vaccinate the minds of our undergraduates against the misconceptions that are so predominant in what passes for educated discussion about international trade.”
Krugman, Paul, 1993, “What Do Undergrads Need to Know About Trade?”
Source: WSJ
President Trump made good on his 2016 campaign pledge to the steel industry, slapping 25% tariffs on foreign-made steel...
The tariffs succeeded in pushing down steel imports and—for a short time—resulted in higher prices for domestic steelmakers...
Yet the tariffs haven’t produced the steelmaking renaissance and robust job growth in America’s industrial heartland that Mr. Trump promised. What’s more, the tariffs have hurt U.S. manufacturers, including those in the automotive and appliance sectors, who say the duties on steel and aluminum continue to keep their metal costs higher than what overseas competitors pay.
“The government picked winners and losers here,”...
Source: WSJ
With the expanded production, about 6,000 jobs were added to the U.S. steel industry’s workforce after tariffs started in 2018, according to the Census Bureau. By the end of 2019, though, those gains evaporated as steel demand and prices sank [but h]igher prices also made steel more expensive for manufacturers that buy it, leading to the loss of about 75,000 U.S. manufacturing jobs, according to a study released late last year by the Federal Reserve Board of Governors.
....I am a Tariff Man. When people or countries come in to raid the great wealth of our Nation, I want them to pay for the privilege of doing so. It will always be the best way to max out our economic power. We are right now taking in $billions in Tariffs. MAKE AMERICA RICH AGAIN
— Donald J. Trump (@realDonaldTrump) December 4, 2018
Source: Reuters
U.S. President Donald Trump says China pays the tariffs he has imposed on $250 billion of Chinese exports to the United States.
But that is not how tariffs work. China’s government and companies in China do not pay tariffs directly. Tariffs are a tax on imports. They are paid by U.S.-registered firms to U.S. customs for the goods they import into the United States.
Importers often pass the costs of tariffs on to customers - manufacturers and consumers in the United States - by raising their prices.
Source: IGA Experts Poll (2012)
Source: IGA Experts Poll (2012)
Source: IGA Experts Poll (2016)
Source: IGA Experts Poll (2018)
Source: IGA Experts Poll (2014)
Source: IGA Experts Poll (2016)
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |