What We've Learned:
What's Left: for good or bad, why do countries have the trade policies they have today?
If you agree with the following premises:
We need to answer two questions:
Unilateral free trade is the theoretically ideal strategy
But this is not good politics!
Political infeasibility of unilateral free trade
Note: opposite of politically stable policy: dispersed benefit, concentrated cost!
Domestic import-competing industries are best-organized political group, stand to lose a large concentrated benefit with free trade
Recall effects of a large country’s tariffs on world trade
Compared to no-tariff, U.S. gains D−(A+B) from tariff
Foreign country loses A+B+D from U.S. tariff
Now consider two big countries: U.S. and China negotiating with one another
If one has a tariff, they gain D−(A+B) and the other loses −(D+E)
If both have tariffs, both lose A+B+E
If neither have tariffs (free trade), they earn 0
Now consider two big countries: U.S. and China negotiating with one another
If you’re having trouble keeping track, let’s simplify
Now consider two big countries: U.S. and China negotiating with one another
If you’re having trouble keeping track, let’s simplify
Nash Equilibrium:
Now consider two big countries: U.S. and China negotiating with one another
If you’re having trouble keeping track, let’s simplify
Nash Equilibrium: (Tariff, Tariff)
Each country has a dominant strategy to give in to political pressure for protectionism
Adam Smith
1723-1790
“[I]t may sometimes be a matter of deliberation [how to remove tariffs] when some foreign nation restrains by high duties or prohibitions the importation of some of our manufactures into their country. Revenge in this case naturally dictates retaliation, and that we should impose the like duties and prohibitions upon the importation of some or all of their manufactures into our country...nations accordingly seldom fail to retaliate in this manner.”
“There may be a good policy in retaliations of this kind...The recovery of a great foreign market will generatlly more than compensate the transitory inconveniency of paying dearer during a short time for some sorts of goods. To judge whether such retaliations are likely to produce such an effect...[belongs] to the skill of that insidious and crafty animal, vulgarly called the statesman or politician, whose councils are directed by the momentary fluctuations of affairs.”
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, (Book IV, Chapter 2
L: Col. Robert Torrens (1780—1864)
R: John Stuart Mill (1806-1873)
“[Reciprocity] would hold out to [foreign countries] a powerful inducement to act upon the principles of reciprocal freedom” - Torrens
“[C]onsiderations of reciprocity...are of material importance when the repeal of duties...is discussed. A country cannot be expected to renounce the power of taxing foreigners, unless foreigners will in return practise towards itself the same forbearance. The only mode in which a country can save itself from being a loser by the duties imposed by other countries on its commodities, is to impose corresponding duties on theirs.” - Mill
Bilateral/multilateral trade agreements provide commitment strategies for each nation to reduce tariffs
Traditionally, it’s concentrated benefits to domestic importers who lobby politicians to put up tariffs
With a trade agreement, domestic exporters (who want free access to foreign markets) act as a concentrated political force fighting to lower tariffs
Creates multiple groups in multiple countries with vested interest in keeping trade open (tariffs down)
More concentrated & strongly interested groups fighting against tariffs than for tariffs!
Odysseus and the Sirens by John William Waterhouse, Scene from Homer's The Odyssey
“We hereby eliminate all tariffs”
There is a reason the public is not allowed into the "room where it happens"
If negotiations were public, or open to Congress:
L: Rep. Willis C. Hawley
R: Sen. Reed Smoot
center[
]
1934 Trade Agreements Act
Authorized the president to negotiate mutual tariff reductions with other countries by up to 50% from Smoot-Hawley tariff
Based on most favored nation (MFN) principle: requires a country to provide any concessions, privileges, or immunities granted to another nation in a trade agreement also to the U.S. (and vice versa)
1947 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
First major multilateral agreement
Set in motion 9 major “rounds” of negotiations through 2001
1947 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
Principle of nondiscrimination:
“Binding” of tariffs: countries may lower tariffs, but are not allowed to raise tariffs (except in exceptional cases)
Resolution of trade disputes through GATT institutions
Protectionist measures in U.S. in 1950s:
1962 Trade Expansion Act: created Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA)
“Uruguay Round” (8th of GATT, 1986-1993, concluded 1994)
World Trade Organization (WTO)
WTO Members, WTO Members dually represented by EU, Observer nations, Non-members
WTO principles:
Organization: Councils for Trade in Goods, Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), Trade in Services, Trade Negotiations Committee
Dispute Resolution Mechanisms
Salvatore, Domenick, 2001, International Eocnomics, 164
2001 China admitted to WTO
2002 Congress granted President “fast-track authority” to negotiate trade deals, expired in 2007
Doha Round (9th of GATT, 2001-?, failed so far)
Disagreements over agricultural subsidies
Debates about GMOs, health and safety issues, environmental protection
Suppose the United States can import T-shirts from Japan or Mexico
Under free trade, U.S. would import 14 Bn from Japan (cheapest), and 0 from Mexico
Suppose the United States can import T-shirts from Japan or Mexico
Suppose instead the U.S. has a 100% tariff on any/all imported T-shirts
Now suppose the U.S. and Mexico enter a free trade agreement
Now Mexican T-shirts (with no tariff) are cheaper at $4/shirt compared with Japan (still with tariff) at $6/shirt!
Trade creation: U.S. imports more T-shirts (compared to under equal tariffs), all from Mexico
Trade diversion: Japan is actually a more efficient producer than Mexico (if no tariffs), but U.S. only trades with Mexico because Japan is outside free trade zone
Increase competition, limit domestic monopoly power
Access to larger markets creates economies of scale
More investment by outside countries to FTA-member countries (to take advantage of larger market) and avoid tariffs
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) between U.S., Canada, and Mexico since 1994
U.S. had a free trade agreement with Canada since 1988/9, wanted to bring Mexico into the fold
2018: rebranded as U.S.-Mexcio-Canada Agreement (USMCA)
Cost of Importing an Automobile to the U.S.
Tripled trade between U.S., Mexico, and Canada
U.S. foreign investment in Mexico increased from $15 billion to $100 billion
Maquiladora: factories in Mexico that import goods from U.S. or abroad, manufacture output, and then export to the U.S. (or elsewhere)
Lower wages and lower tariffs
Before NAFTA: 47% maquila employment growth (564 new plants)
Effects on U.S.: modest, increased GDP by 0.5%, or $80 billion
Concentrated costs (U.S. manufacturing & automobiles) but dispersed benefits to consumers
Est. 14 million jobs depend on trade with Canada and Mexico, 200,000 export related jobs created annually, paying 15-20% more on average than jobs lost to NAFTA
Companies moving many factories to Mexico, U.S. auto sector lost 350,000 jobs since 1994; Mexican auto sector increased from 120,000 to 500,000 jobs
Est. 15,000 net jobs lost each year but economy gains $450,000 in higher productivity gains and lower consumer prices
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |